BILL ANALYSIS ---------------------------------------------------------- | Hearing Date: April 25, 2005 |Bill No: SB | | |582 | ---------------------------------------------------------- SENATE COMMITTEE ON BUSINESS, PROFESSIONS AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT Senator Liz Figueroa, Chair Bill No: SB 582 Author: Figueroa As Amended: April 11, 2005 Fiscal: Yes SUBJECT: Retailers: Disclosures. SUMMARY: Requires that (1) retailers provide information to a vendor of a product regarding the discounts and stocking fees offered by other vendors to place similar products on the shelf; (2) retailers share market information equally with all vendors. Existing state law: 1) Prohibits manufacturers and distributors of alcoholic beverages from paying retailers for any services such as stocking, advertising, or storage. Violation of these provisions is a misdemeanor. 2) Prohibits vendors from offering rebates for the purpose of injuring or destroying competition under the California Unfair Practices Act. 3) Prohibits two parties from entering into a contract with the explicit purpose of restraining competition under the California Cartwright Act. Existing Federal Law under the Robinson-Patman Act: 1)Prohibits a party from charging different prices for the same product or services when price discrimination has the effect of injuring SB 582 Page 2 competition. 2)Prohibits a party from paying or receiving a commission or brokerage fee in relation to a sale of goods unless something of value is exchanged in return. Existing Federal Law under the Sherman Antitrust Act, prohibits two or more parties from entering into an agreement for the purpose of restraining trade. Existing Federal Law under the Clayton Act, prohibits a party from creating or attempting to maintain a monopoly through tactics that exclude or significantly impair the ability of other firms to enter the market. This bill: 1) Requires a retailer to disclose shelf placement fee information about products within 10 feet of the products most similar to those offered by a vendor or qualified potential vendor. 2) Requires that if a retailer shares sales or promotional information with a vendor about a competitor's products that the retailer must share the same sales and promotional information with all other vendors of similar products. 3) Provides that a qualified vendor can recover a $10,000 civil penalty, attorney's fees and court costs from a retailer who fails to comply with the provisions of the bill. FISCAL EFFECT: Unknown. This bill has been keyed "fiscal" by Legislative Counsel. COMMENTS: 1.Purpose. This bill is sponsored by the Author. According to the Author, SB 582 will bring SB 582 Page 3 transparency to California's retail trades and assure that small manufacturers and suppliers have a chance to compete for shelf space in California's retail outlets. According to the Author, shelf placement fees and the preferential relationships between retailers and suppliers can be used anticompetitively. However, because these relationships are secretive it is difficult for either regulators or other vendors to know when abuses are occurring. This bill requires retailers to share information with product vendors about what types of relationships the retailer has with other vendors so that small vendors can compete with other vendors and monitor abuses. 2.Background on Shelf Placement Fees. Shelf placement fees, also called "slotting fees," are the fees paid by suppliers and manufacturers to retailers in order to introduce a new product. It can be expensive for a retailer to introduce a new product into a store. In order to share the risk of shelf placement, retailers charge manufacturers a shelf placement fee. It is also increasingly common for retailers to charge slow moving products "pay-to-stay" fees to recoup some of the cost of continuing to carry a slow moving product. In 2000 the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) estimated that vendors pay $9 billion in shelf placement fees annually to the grocery industry alone. Other studies have suggested that the number may be as high as $16 billion. Although shelf placement fees are predominantly in the grocery industry, they have also been reported in a number of other retail industries including books, cameras, movies and software. Shelf placement fees do not necessarily relate to the cost of putting items on the shelf. In 2003 the FTC found that although all of the stores they surveyed had shelf placement fees for some products, the percentage of products affected as a ratio of SB 582 Page 4 new products ranged from 6% to 65.2%. The category of average fee per chain ranged from $500 to $28,921, one particular chain had slotting fees ranging from $500 to $15,820 depending on the category. Categories, such as Ice Cream saw average slotting fees as high as $28,921 and as low as $4,125. Shelf placement fees are not always cash. Small manufacturers that have spoken to Committee staff confidentially have detailed a variety of shelf placement fee arrangements which include a promise of free goods, contributions to year-end parties, participation in promotional programs, guaranteed advertising buys, and discounts on other products. Shelf placement fees are generally not recorded or disclosed. A 1997 study of shelf placement fees found that 93% of food vendors did not know what fees other vendors of similar products paid for shelf space. It is not common practice in the food industry to provide contracts or receipts of shelf placement fees paid. One manufacturer told Committee staff that he had paid $170,000 to place a product on stores throughout California and was unable to get a written guarantee that his product would actually be placed. 3.Background on Category Captaincy: Category Captaincy is the general term given to a range of practices in which a retailer relies on dominant vendors to assist with making product selection, placement, pricing, and promotion decisions. In 2001 the FTC observed that "even the very largest retailers are less well-informed about particular product areas than the manufacturers, and can thus benefit from their assistance." In 2003 the FTC found that 5 of the 7 grocery chains that participated in its survey used Category Captains. Category Captains participate in managing both their own and their competitors' products. Although the SB 582 Page 5 arrangements varied, the FTC noted that "a key component of the category captaincy is . . . the sharing of category specific information, data, expertise, and analysis." This sensitive information is not generally shared with smaller vendors who are not privy to the Category Captain relationship. A 2003 study conducted by Debra Desrochers found that 84% of Category Captains participated in the programs because they believed they could influence product placement decisions and advantage their products over their competitors. 4.The Special Case of Alcohol: Federal law through the Federal Alcohol Administration Act of 1935 (FAAA) prohibits any practice which threatened the independence of retailers from alcohol manufacturers. In 1992, the D.C court of appeals observed that the special treatment of alcohol was designed to serve the two goals of trying to: (1) limit the "unique threat of corruption in the newly-legal alcohol industry" and, (2) "positively promote a competitive alcohol market." Federal regulators prohibit shelf placement fees because they view them as a threat to retailer independence. Additionally, in 1953 California prohibited breweries, distilleries and wineries from giving anything of value to retailers of liquor, with a few statutory exceptions, for coasters, beer taps, and similar products. 5.Regulation of Shelf Placement Fees and Category Captaincy in Other Jurisdictions. Federal: There has been no federal regulation of either shelf placement fees or category captaincy. In 2003, the FTC issued a report detailing the various arguments for how shelf placement fees and captaincy can benefit and hurt competition. In SB 582 Page 6 conclusion, the FTC stated that because of the limited data they were able to collect "it is not possible to determine with confidence which, if any, of the discussed economic theories best explain why suppliers pay retailers slotting fees." Canada: The Canadian Competition Bureau (CCB), the equivalent to the FTC in the United States, issued a bulletin in November 2002 indicating that it would take action if "payment of slotting allowances [shelf placement fees] is being used by dominant firms(s) to acquire exclusivity or to tie up enough of the available shelf space to preclude other competitors from entering or expanding into the market." The bulletin went on to include category captaincy as a suspect practice because the CCB found that category captaincy facilitates interdependence and tacit collusion among firms. Israel: In 2003, the General Director of the Antitrust Authority issued a directive outlawing many types of shelf placement fees, requiring that shelf placement decisions be made by retailers, independent of suppliers, and prohibited retailers from sharing market information with a supplier's competitors, in effect outlawing category captaincy. 6.Court Cases Related to the Use of Slotting Fees and Category Captaincy. Brought by Vendors: In Conwood v. United States Tobacco, 290 F.3d 268 (2002), the court found that United States Tobacco Corporation, the maker of 77% of chewing tobacco, used its position as category manager to exclude competition by suggesting that retailers carry fewer products, particularly competitor's products; attempting to control the number of price value brands introduced in stores; and by suggesting that stores carry its slower moving products instead of better selling competitor products. The court awarded Conwood $1.05 Billion, SB 582 Page 7 the largest anti-trust award in United States history. In El Aguila Food Products v. Gruma Corporation, 301 F. Supp. 2d 612 (S.D. Tex. 2003) (currently on appeal, 5th Circuit in Federal Court), the plaintiff, a Salinas, California tortilla maker, presented evidence to show that Gruma, a competitor, was paying excessive slotting fees to gain control of the tortilla market. El Aguila submitted documents from Gruma in which Gruma stated, "If Gruma can duplicate its California retail position in Texas, Gruma can effectively block future meaningful competition." Furthermore, the plaintiff presented testimony that the money which Gruma paid for slotting fees did not come from tortilla sales. Instead Gruma had invested money earned elsewhere to buy shelf space. Brought by Consumers: In, Diaz v. Gruma, CASE NO BC. 316086, Los Angeles Superior Court, filed August 6, 2004, plaintiff, a member of the general public, brought action against Gruma and assorted grocery stores for entering into exclusivity contracts and paying excessive slotting fees with the intent of forcing its competitors out of the Southern California tortilla market so that they could charge excessive prices. At the time of filing, Gruma controlled 90% of the Southern California tortilla market. Brought by Retailers: In American Booksellers Assn. v. Barnes & Noble, 135 F.Supp.2d 1031 (N. Dist. Cal. 2001), plaintiffs, consisting of 27 independent California booksellers, brought action against large chain bookstores arguing that "the large booksellers have received secret discounts and other favorable terms from booksellers that are not available to independent bookstores." The court found that the independent booksellers had provided evidence of the conduct, however the case settled out of court before a final decision could be reached. SB 582 Page 8 In Alan's of Atlanta v. Minolta Corporation, 903 F.2d 1414 (11th Cir. 1990), plaintiffs, a small camera distributor, brought action against Minolta for not offering it proportionately equivalent participation in Minolta's key retailer program as it offered one of the plaintiff's competitors. On summary judgment, the court held that providing discounts and services to one retailer without offering the same services to another was grounds for a violation of the Robinson-Patman Act. 7.Informational Hearing of the Business, Professions and Economic Development Committee on February 9, 2005. At the February 9th informational hearing the committee heard testimony from national experts, small businesses that have been impacted by shelf placement fees, grocery store workers responsible for enforcing shelf placement arrangements, as well as representatives from the United Food and Commercial Workers Union and the California Grocery Association. Speakers discussed both the advantages and potential harm associated with shelf placement fees and category captaincy, and raised many of the arguments and issues that are reflected in their support and opposition to this measure in Items #8 and #9 of the analysis. The Author drafted the bill in response to the concerns and recommendations of many of the parties that testified at the informational hearing. 8.Arguments in Support. It is inherently unfair for retailers to privately share information about a vendor with that vendor's competitor. The supporters of this bill argue that common practice of sharing information with only a select supplier about that supplier's competitors, disadvantages the suppliers which do not have access to information. Furthermore, one-sided disclosure invites preferred suppliers to behave anticompetitively as they did in the Conwood case discussed above. SB 582 Page 9 Transparency benefits small product manufacturers. The supporters of this bill argue that without transparency small product manufacturers are unable to meet their competition and unaware when shelf placement fees and Category Captaincy are being used anticompetitively. By making information public, small producer manufacturers will be able to (1) strategically compete for shelf space in markets where their products are wanted, and (2) learn when they are being excluded from shelves by anticompetitive practices and take proper action under current law. Why small producers are beneficial to California. The supporters of this bill argue that protecting California's small producer manufacturers is good for California for two reasons: (1) small product manufacturers are more likely to be from California and employ Californians than large manufacturers, and (2) small product manufacturers are more often the innovators that keep California's economy dynamic and growing. Transparency benefits retailers. The supporters of this bill believe that fair competition among producers will benefit retailers in three ways: (1) by creating a competitive bidding market for California's shelves, supporters believe that in many categories shelf placement fees are likely to increase to accurately reflect the actual risk associated with new product introduction; (2) when large suppliers put small suppliers out of business retailers are in a disadvantaged negotiating position; and (3) retailers will be better able to select successful products if suppliers are able to offer competing evidence about a product. Transparency benefits consumers. The supporters of this bill believe that the ultimate beneficiaries of this bill are California's consumers. Protecting competition assures that new innovative products SB 582 Page 10 will continue to be available at affordable prices. When competition is thwarted, consumers overpay for inferior products and are unable to buy specialty products. Why transparency is necessary when anticompetitive practices are already prohibited? Supporters of this bill argue that when the arrangements between retailers and suppliers are secret it is impossible for a supplier to know of anticompetitive practices without bringing a lawsuit and compelling discovery. Even when a supplier suspects an anticompetitive practice, it often does not make good business sense to bring a lawsuit unless they have strong evidence. Why a $10,000 fine payable to plaintiffs is necessary? The supporters of this bill believe that due to the frequency and complexity of vendor retailer negotiations it is impractical for the state to effectively monitor disclosure. However, without a payable fine it will be hard for private parties to finance lawsuits. The amount $10,000 is consistent with the fines already imposed for violation of existing restrictions on the relationships between alcoholic beverage producers and retailers. 9.Arguments in Opposition Prior to Amended Version of April 11, 2005. Transparency will enable anticompetitive behavior. The California Retailers Association (CRA) and the California Grocers Association (CGA) argue that disclosing shelf placement fees will induce anticompetitive behavior. This view was also shared in the February 9th hearing in this committee. Opponents make two arguments on anticompetitive behavior: (1) that by disclosing shelf placement fees, large suppliers will be able to raise their shelf placement offer in order to displace smaller SB 582 Page 11 competitors; and, (2) that by disclosing shelf placement fees large suppliers will be able to coordinate the amount they offer for shelf placement allowances. The opponents also argue that the bill is virtually unenforceable because "shelf placement fees come in all forms, colors, flavors, shapes and sizes." Supporters answer these criticisms generally by pointing out that both of the practices which opponents believe could occur are not possible today and illegal. By forcing transparency on retailers practices involving slotting fees and category captaincy, supporters argue that they will become aware of anticompetitive practices and be able to contest them. As far as this measure being unenforceable, supporters answer this criticism by pointing to provisions regulating shelf placement fees for alcoholic beverages that have effectively prohibited shelf placement fees in California since 1953. NOTE: Double-referral to Senate Judiciary Committee. SUPPORT AND OPPOSITION: Support: A Perfect Pear from Napa Valley, Napa Consumer Federation of CA El Aguila Tortilla, Salinas, CA Filipino-American Chamber of Commerce Food Industry Roundtable (FIBR) Kiyomura-Ishimoto Associates La Bonita Tortilla, Bakersfield, CA Lawrence Equipment, So. El Monte, CA Llorena Family Brand, Los Angeles, CA Mi Rancho Tortilla, Clovis, CA Monterrey County Farm Bureau UFCW Local 870 SB 582 Page 12 Opposition: California Grocers Association California Retailers Association Charles Magowan, TradePoint Solutions, Inc. Consultants: Nathaniel Leeds/Doug Brown