BILL ANALYSIS 1 1 SENATE ENERGY, UTILITIES AND COMMUNICATIONS COMMITTEE DEBRA BOWEN, CHAIRWOMAN SB 888 - Dunn, Bowen, and Burton Hearing Date: May 6, 2003 S As Amended: April 28, 2003 FISCAL B 8 8 8 DESCRIPTION This bill enacts the "Repeal of Electricity Deregulation Act of 2003," which repeals or modifies specified "deregulation" policies established by AB 1890 (Brulte), Chapter 856, Statutes of 1996, confirms and expands upon certain recently-enacted "regulation" policies, and spells out the rights and obligations of utilities, ratepayers and the California Public Utilities Commission (CPUC) in the state-regulated aspects of electricity service. This bill's key objective is to avoid a recurrence of the instability and high cost of the past few years by: 1.Confirming a regulatory compact. 2.Restoring long-term resource planning. 3.Phasing out retail competition. Specifically, this bill : 1.Repeals AB 1890's extensive legislative findings supporting electricity deregulation and instead establishes extensive new findings citing the failures of deregulation and supporting state regulation of electricity service. Requires CPUC actions to be consistent with the bill's findings. (Sections 1, 3 & 5). 2.States legislative intent to achieve effective regulation of public utilities and achieve the following policy goals (Section 4): a. Restore and affirm the utilities' obligation to serve. b. Eliminate opportunities for market manipulation associated with power plant divestiture. c. Ensure reliability and deter market manipulation through effective power plant maintenance and operation standards. d. Provide for cost-effective investments in transmission and distribution, with reasonable rates of return. e. Require metering, billing, collection and customer service to be provided by CPUC-regulated utilities. f. End utility employee layoffs and provide reasonable wages and working conditions. g. Establish an integrated resource planning process that results in a balanced, reliable, environmentally responsible portfolio of supply and demand reduction resources. h. Prioritize cost-effective energy efficiency and renewable resources in resource planning. i. Require transparent corporate ownership of utilities, improve accountability for holding company requirements, and seek enforcement of the federal Public Utility Holding Company Act (PUHCA). j. Provide for fair allocation of electricity costs through CPUC-set rates, rather than direct access. aa. Restore consumer and investor confidence by making utility costs transparent and establishing and enforcing accounting standards. bb. Assure universal service with affordable rates and discounts for low-income customers. cc. Provide an open regulatory forum where affected parties can observe and participate. 1.Codifies an explicit "regulatory compact" governing the rights and obligations of investor-owned utilities (IOUs) and the CPUC. Under the regulatory compact, IOUs have an obligation to serve all customers in their service area, including specified duties, and the CPUC has an obligation to provide IOUs a reasonable opportunity to recover their investments, including a reasonable rate of return (Section 6). 2.Transfers responsibility for inspection, maintenance, repair and replacement standards for IOU transmission facilities from the Independent System Operator (ISO) to the CPUC (Sections 13 & 21). 3.Prohibits the ISO from entering a multi-state regional transmission organization unless approved by the Legislature by concurrent resolution (Section 15). 4.Repeals AB 1890's provisions authorizing, and requiring the CPUC to facilitate, direct access electricity service. Phases out existing direct access by requiring existing direct access customers to receive retail service from their IOU once their current direct access contracts expire. Expressly permits community aggregation and self-generation service options (Sections 22-26, 30, 37, 38). 5.Requires IOUs to hold in trust, for the benefit of ratepayers, any refunds for excessive electricity costs that the IOU has recovered or will recover from ratepayers (Section 28). 6.Requires the CPUC to regulate IOU power plants on a cost-of-service basis (confirming the existing practice) and extends the current prohibition on power plant divestiture from 2006 to 2010 (Section 33). 7.Requires IOU customers' electricity metering and billing to be performed by IOUs. Prohibits charging time-of-use or real-time rates to residential or small commercial customers without customer consent (Sections 39 & 40). 8.Requires the CPUC to establish and oversee a "long-term, comprehensive integrated resource planning process" that results in a balanced, reliable, environmentally responsible portfolio of supply and demand reduction resources and is consistent with existing laws related to procurement of renewable resources and energy planning and forecasting. Requires IOUs to implement their procurement plans consistent with the long-term plan and in a manner that gives priority to acquiring cost-effective energy efficiency resources (Section 42). 9.Changes a standard governing recovery of IOU transmission investments from "facilitating competition" to "providing lower cost delivery of electricity" (Section 43). 10. Authorizes the CPUC to require an IOU to invest directly in, or contract for, power plants as a non-exclusive means of fulfilling its obligation to serve. Requires such investments to be consistent with the IOU's approved procurement plan and existing laws related to procurement of electricity, and renewable resources in particular (Section 44). 11. Authorizes the CPUC to monitor and enforce IOU holding companies' compliance with the conditions of the CPUC's approval of the formation of the holding companies (Section 45). 12. Repeals various obsolete provisions of AB 1890, including provisions related to the recovery of uneconomic costs by IOUs during the 1998-2002 transition period, provisions related to the now-defunct Power Exchange (PX), and provisions related to publicly-owned utilities' participation in direct access, and makes conforming amendments to other sections (Sections 7-12, 14, 16-20, 27, 29, 31, 32, 34-36, 41 & 46-51). KEY POLICY QUESTIONS 1.Should electric utility planning, investment and rate-setting be conducted in public processes and subject to regulatory oversight, or should these decisions be led by the private sector? 2.How can the state best assure investment in the electricity infrastructure necessary to meet the needs of IOU customers and consistent with California's policy priorities (i.e., reliable, affordable, efficient and diverse electricity service)? BACKGROUND Historical Context - 1900-1996 The early electric power industry was developed using direct current transmission, a system in which a relatively low voltage of electricity could travel only over short distances. Typically, numerous power plants were built within a small densely populated area, usually a city, and consumers were able to choose their service provider. This structure created much competition within a local marketplace. This paradigm began to change as technology rapidly transformed the industry. Newer machines, such as steam turbines, were smaller and less complex, and could create a greater amount of power with a much smaller capital investment. The discovery of alternating current transformers allowed companies to transport power over longer distances at a higher voltage. Savvy entrepreneurs, such as Samuel Insull of Chicago Edison, realized they could exploit the greater economies of scale afforded by these new technologies, and maximize profits by consolidating the smaller utility companies. Fueled by the rapid growth of electricity consumption, the utilities boomed during the early 20th century. By 1907, Insull had acquired 20 other utility companies and renamed his firm Commonwealth Edison. He and others argued that electric utilities were a "natural monopoly" because it would be inefficient to build multiple transmission and distribution systems due to the great expense of capital investment. Therefore, it was inherent that only one company would dominate the market. The emerging utility monopolies were vertically integrated, meaning they controlled the generation of electric power, its transmission in real time across high-voltage wires, and its low-voltage distribution to homes and businesses. Reformers of the Progressive Era tried to govern these emerging utility monopolies through state regulation. By 1914, 43 states (including California) had established regulatory polices governing electric utilities. As their businesses grew, the new electric power barons such as Insull began to restructure their companies, largely through the use of holding companies. A holding company is a company that controls a partial or complete interest in another company, and it can be a useful tool in consolidating the operations of several smaller companies. However, the electric utilities of the 1920s began to exploit the use of holding companies to buy up smaller utilities in an effort designed not to improve the company's operating efficiency, but as a speculative attempt to maximize profits. The growing utility monopolies then exploited this structure, pyramiding holding company on top of holding company, sometimes such that a holding company was as many as ten times removed from the operating company. Each new holding company would buy a controlling interest in the holding company below it and the additional costs and fees for the operating companies were passed along in a higher rate base for the consumer. While the operating companies were subject to state regulation, the holding companies were not; therefore each holding company could issue fresh stocks and bonds without state oversight. The abuse of holding companies allowed for the consolidation of utilities such that by the end of the 1920s, ten utility systems controlled three-fourths of the United States' electric power business. The size and complexities of the holding companies were proving state regulation of utilities ineffective and soon caught the attention of the federal government. In 1928, the Federal Trade Commission began a six-year investigation into the market manipulations of the holding companies. The booming utilities of the 1920s traditionally had been seen as relatively secure investments, and utility stocks were held by millions of investors. The pyramidal holding company structure allowed the holding companies to inflate the value of utility securities, which eventually were decimated by the 1929 stock market crash. Elected to the presidency in 1932, Franklin Delano Roosevelt fought vehemently against the holding companies, calling them "evil" in his 1935 State-of-the-Union address. After a hard-fought campaign by the president and his allies, and in the face of bitter opposition from the utilities, Congress passed the Public Utility Holding Company Act in 1935. PUHCA outlawed the pyramidal structure of interstate utility holding companies, determining that they could be no more than twice removed from their operating subsidiaries. It required holding companies that owned 10% or more of a public utility to register with the Securities and Exchange Commission and provide detailed accounts of their financial transactions and holdings. Holding companies that operated within a single state were exempt from PUHCA. The legislation had a dramatic effect on the operations of holding companies: Between 1938 and 1958 the number of holding companies declined from 216 to 18. This forced divestiture led to a new paradigm for the electricity marketplace which lasted until the deregulation of the 1980s and 1990s: a single vertically-integrated system which served a circumscribed geographic area regulated by either the state or federal government. Roosevelt made the fight for public power an integral part of his New Deal campaign and pushed for other important legislation to that end. In the same year as PUHCA, Congress passed the Federal Power Act of 1935, which gave the Federal Power Commission (FPC) regulatory power over interstate and wholesale transactions and transmission of electric power. The FPC had been established under the Federal Water Power Act of 1920 to encourage the development of hydroelectric power plants. The Commission originally consisted of the secretaries of war, interior and agriculture. The Federal Power Act changed the structure of the FPC so it consisted of five commissioners nominated by the president, with the stipulation that no more than three commissioners could come from the same political party. The Federal Power Act gave the FPC a mandate to ensure electricity rates that are "reasonable, nondiscriminatory and just to the consumer." Another component of FDR's fight for public power was the creation of federal agencies to distribute power to those who were neglected by the traditional utilities, particularly farmers and other customers in rural areas. His administration created the Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA) in 1933 and the Rural Electrification Association (REA) in 1935 to create and finance rural utility companies. The end result of the New Deal era regulatory intervention into the electric industry led to four primary types of service providers: private investor-owned utilities with stock freely traded in the marketplace by shareholders; publicly-owned utilities, such as those owned by municipalities; cooperative utilities which were usually found in rural communities; and federal electric utilities, such as the TVA and REA. After the tumult of the Roosevelt years and the end of World War II, the electric power industry enjoyed a period of steady growth, driven by both technological and efficiency advances that were reflected in lower prices. Between 1947 to 1973, the growth rate for the industry held steady at about 8% per year and there was little change in the industry structure. The industry began to promote increased electricity usage through advertising campaigns with slogans such as GE's "Live Better Electrically" campaign begun in 1956. As the industry grew and prices continued to decline, there was little need for state and federal regulatory intervention. IOUs were the primary service providers for most Americans and their continued growth and low rates satisfied both consumers and investors. The energy crisis of the 1970s is often symbolized by images of long lines at gas pumps all over the United States resulting from the 1973 OPEC oil embargo. Oil, coal and natural gas shortages, as well as declining public confidence in the nuclear power industry, contributed to rate increases for consumers throughout all the energy industries, including electricity. Elected in 1976, President Jimmy Carter made energy concerns one of his top priorities. In attacking the demand side of the problem, he waged a public campaign focused on conservation to reduce the American public's high rates of energy consumption. To combat the supply side, he sought to cultivate the growth of new sources of energy, including nuclear power and renewable resources such as solar and wind power. These two approaches were crystallized in the five-part National Energy Act, which Carter signed into law in 1978. The Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act (PURPA) was the piece of Carter's National Energy Act that affected the electric power industry. It was designed to encourage efficient use of fossil fuels by allowing non-utility generators (known as Qualifying Facilities or QFs) to enter the wholesale power market. PURPA designated two main categories of QFs: co-generators, which use a single fuel source to either sequentially or simultaneously produce electric energy as well as another form of energy, such as heat or steam; and independent power producers, which use renewable resources including solar, wind, biomass, geothermal and hydroelectric power as their primary energy source. Although intended to be an environmental statute, a primary effect of PURPA was to introduce competition into the generation sector of the electricity marketplace, thus challenging the utilities' claim that the electricity market encouraged a "natural monopoly." One year prior to the National Energy Act, President Carter signed the Department of Energy Organization Act. The act created the Department of Energy by consolidating organizational entities from a dozen department and agencies. Under this legislation, the FPC was replaced by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) as the federal agency that establishes and enforces wholesale electricity rates. The free-market mania of the 1980s and 1990s further challenged the notion of the electric power industry as a "natural monopoly." Many politicians and economists argued regulation had outlived its value, and the market should determine prices. The telecommunications and transportation industries were deregulated, and the natural gas industry followed suit. Advocates for deregulating the electricity industry argued the implementation of PURPA had proved non-utility generators could produce power as inexpensively and effectively as the regulated utilities. Large industrial consumers searching for lower prices also chimed in and urged federal regulators to pursue deregulation. In 1992, Congress passed President Bush's Energy Policy Act (EPACT), which opened access to transmission networks to non-utility generators. EPACT further facilitated the development of a competitive market by creating another category of generators known as exempt wholesale generators (EWGs), which were exempted from regulations faced by the traditional utilities. To assist in the implementation of PURPA and EPACT, FERC issued Orders 888 and 889 in April 1996. The two orders provided guidelines on how to open electricity transmission networks on a nondiscriminatory basis in interstate commerce. Source: PBS Frontline - http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/pages/frontline/shows/blackout AB 1890 and the Retail Side of Electricity Deregulation The push toward electricity deregulation at the federal level led states with relatively high electricity rates, including California, to investigate and pursue deregulation of the state-regulated aspects of electricity service, and retail service in particular. In California, the push was led by large industrial customers facing high electricity costs and an ailing economy. These customers saw advantage in bypassing the IOUs "bundled service" and buying electricity directly from suppliers. The industrial customers were joined in the push for deregulation by merchant generators and marketers, who wanted to compete on equal footing with the IOUs and sell electricity and related services to selected profitable customers. The IOUs, who saw promising ventures in deregulated electricity markets for themselves, favored deregulation once their primary concern about recovery of investments stranded by the departure of their customers to competitors was satisfied. In 1996, electricity deregulation, or "restructuring," legislation was passed by the Legislature. AB 1890 codified a series of deregulation proposals either undertaken or recommended by the CPUC, whose work on deregulation had been inspired by the EPACT and subsequent FERC policies. Chief among the CPUC proposals was "direct access" - the authorization of retail competition within IOU service areas. AB 1890 ended the retail service monopoly of utilities and authorized retail customers to buy power directly from alternative providers, beginning in 1998. The essential bargain of AB 1890 was to authorize direct access and assure the IOU's could recover stranded investments, but the CPUC's implementing decisions took a series of further steps, intended to facilitate competition, and direct access in particular, which would prove disastrous. These included compelling the IOUs to sell off the power plants that generated the electricity needed to serve their own customers, requiring the IOUs to buy and sell all their power through the PX and ISO spot markets, and retreating from long-term planning and investment. Other elements of deregulation, such as the IOUs' transfer of control of their transmission systems to the ISO to facilitate non-discriminatory access to competing suppliers, were addressed in AB 1890, but likely would have happened anyway pursuant to federal policies, such as FERC's Order 888. The main contribution of AB 1890 in this area, which was to attempt to ensure accountability of the ISO to the state, met with limited success. AB 1890 also contained a number of side deals. These included a guaranteed 10% reduction in retail rates for small customers, a guaranteed level of funding for low-income and environmental public purpose programs, and assistance for IOU employees whose jobs would be at risk. The final product was widely supported. At the time, deregulation champions heralded the bill as paving the way for more competitive, efficient, reliable, and affordable electricity service. Many would-be critics saw deregulation in California as inevitable and AB 1890 as the best possible bargain. Few questions were asked. AB 1890 passed without a single "NO" vote. The Collapse of the AB 1890 Edifice In the first two years after its implementation, the deregulation experiment appeared to be paying off well for IOUs and customers alike in California. Service remained reliable, wholesale prices remained below the frozen retail rates, and the IOUs' stranded cost recovery surged, due in large part to the unexpectedly high prices fetched for the sale of their power plants. Large rate reductions were anticipated once the transition period was over. Evidence of market power began to surface in 1999. Irregular but enormous price spikes in spot energy and ancillary services markets raised concerns among observers. The potential for market power abuse and increased prices was at the forefront of skepticism over Pacific Gas & Electric (PG&E) Company's failed attempt divest its entire hydroelectric system to an unregulated affiliate. The Legislature's refusal to permit the PG&E divestiture was the first major hiccup in the march toward deregulation. Then, in mid-2000, unprecedented price spikes began to occur with growing regularity. In San Diego, where the rate freeze had ended, San Diego Gas & Electric (SDG&E) customers were directly exposed to the high prices. Within six months, the market was in disarray, rolling blackouts occurred during periods of relatively low electricity demand, suppliers' demands for extraordinary prices were unchecked, high wholesale prices caused nearly all customers of the collapsing direct access market to return to the IOUs' frozen rates, the IOUs became financially unable to pay for electricity, and the state had to assume the IOUs' power buying duties to "keep the lights on." To avoid the dysfunctional spot market that financially decimated the IOUs and threatened catastrophic rate increases, AB 1X (Keeley), Chapter 4, Statutes of 2001, established a structure to permit the Department of Water Resources (DWR) to buy needed electricity for IOU customers under long-term contracts. To ensure the predictable revenue stream necessary for long-term contracts, the issuance of ratepayer-backed revenue bonds, and prevent cost-shifting from direct access to bundled service customers, the CPUC was directed to suspend direct access to prevent additional migration of IOU customers. After a seven-month delay, the CPUC suspended direct access on September 20, 2001. Between January and June 2001, the vast majority of customers previously served by direct access providers returned to IOU service, benefiting from retail rates which were lower and more stable than market prices. However, between July 1, 2001 and September 20, 2001, thousands of predominantly large industrial customers, who had taken service from the state at below-market rates, departed for direct access as market conditions improved. During the July 1 to September 20 period, direct access increased from approximately 2% to approximately 13% of the total IOU load. Direct access load continues to grow due to the CPUC's liberal interpretation of the Legislature's direction to suspend direct access, including allowing customers to begin direct access service after the suspension date and switch between bundled service and direct access service. The Consequences for IOU Customers Since early 2001, the electricity rates set by the CPUC for the customers of the state's major IOUs have exceeded the IOUs' ongoing cost of service, far exceeding the rates of in-state municipal utilities or any neighboring state, and ranking among the highest in the nation. In January, and again in March, 2001, the CPUC increased rates for the customers of Southern California Edison (SCE) and PG&E a combined average of 4 cents per kilowatt hour. High-usage residential customers and the vast majority of business customers who take bundled service were hit especially hard. The rate increases marked the practical collapse of the rate freeze and transition cost recovery scheme created by AB 1890. While DWR has claimed a share of electricity rates for its ongoing operating costs and payments on bonds it issued to finance its high-cost power purchases in 2001, the IOUs have also been collecting an extra measure of rates that would otherwise be dedicated to buying electricity. Under the CPUC rate increase decisions, these extra rates were subject to refund to utility customers. However, the CPUC has maintained these higher rates, instead of refunding the excess funds to customers or using them for ongoing procurement, and expanded their purposes to include restoring the financial health of SCE and PG&E. For example, in October 2001, the CPUC entered a settlement of federal litigation with SCE permitting SCE to use excess rates to pay off about $3.6 billion of procurement debts incurred in 2000. Since then, SCE has been applying an average of about $200 million per month in rates to pay these debts. A challenge to the settlement by The Utility Reform Network (TURN) is now pending in the California Supreme Court. In November 2002, the CPUC issued a unanimous decision (D.02-11-026), applicable to both SCE and PG&E, lifting its prior restriction on the use of the 2001 rate increases and allowing the money to be used for "returning each utility to financial health." Sometime in 2003, SCE's and PG&E's accumulation of excess rates should match their historic procurement debts, leaving little excuse for continuing today's high rates. Once the debts are paid, rates can be reduced, or dedicated to some purpose other than payment of past IOU debts. SCE has filed a petition to reduce its rates which, if approved by the CPUC, would take effect later this year. Meanwhile, the CPUC has proposed to dedicate a share of the excess rates to a loan program to defer direct access customers' payment of DWR and IOU procurement costs. In a decision issued in November 2002 (D.02-11-022), the CPUC capped the payment for these costs applicable to direct access customers at 2.7 cents per kilowatt hour. The CPUC majority (Commissioners Peevey, Brown and Duque) reasoned such a cap was necessary to maintain the viability of existing direct access contracts. 2.7 cents won't pay back what direct access customers owe for DWR power already delivered, or for DWR operating costs in the next few years, so a revenue shortfall or "under-collection" results. Since payment of DWR's costs (bond payment and ongoing revenue requirement) can't be postponed, the CPUC decision shifts the obligation to pay any shortfall from direct access customers to each IOU's bundled customers, be they residential, agricultural, commercial or industrial. According to the CPUC, the direct access shortfall as of January 1, 2003 was $609 million. Although collection of the surcharge from direct access customers began on January 1, the under-collection of DWR's share has been exacerbated by IOUs' failure to remit a share of the charges to DWR. The CPUC estimates the shortfall will grow for several years and peak at nearly $2 billion. Over time (perhaps 10-15 years), as DWR costs decline, direct access customers' payments are projected to catch up and pay off this under-collection. In the meantime, IOU customer rates will have to maintained at a level high enough to support this "forced loan" to direct access customers. Post-AB 1890 Retreat from Deregulation In addition to the emergency enactment of AB 1X, other state laws enacted during and since the energy crisis have emphasized maintaining and enhancing publicly-accountable, state and/or local control over electricity planning, investment and rate-setting. Examples include: AB 5X (Keeley), Chapter 1, Statutes of 2001-2002, and SB 47 (Bowen), Chapter 766, Statutes of 2001, provided for gubernatorial appointment and Senate confirmation of the ISO board. AB 6X (Dutra), Chapter 2, Statutes of 2001-2002, put an end to market valuation and divestiture of IOU power plants. AB 57 (Wright), Chapter 835, Statutes of 2002, established a CPUC-regulated procurement planning and cost recovery process for IOUs. SB 6X (Burton), Chapter 10, Statutes of 2001-2002, established the Power Authority to facilitate public investment in cost-based electricity resources. SB 39XX (Burton), Chapter 19, Statutes of 2001-2002, authorized the CPUC and ISO to establish inspection and maintenance standards for merchant power plants to ensure their availability. SB 1078 (Sher), Chapter 516, Statutes of 2002, required IOUs to increase procurement of renewable resources subject to a process overseen by the CPUC. SB 1389 (Bowen), Chapter 568, Statutes of 2002, required the Energy Commission to prepare an Integrated Energy Policy Report every two years based on its assessment of trends in energy markets, including electricity. During and since the energy crisis, the state has also actively challenged FERC policies and enforcement practices at FERC and in the courts. COMMENTS 1.Comparison of major features (pre-AB 1890, AB 1890 and SB 888). Electricity deregulation is typified by dis-integration, or "unbundling," of the three major elements of vertically-integrated utility service - generation, transmission, and retail service. The following is a comparison of the operation of these elements prior to AB 1890, under AB 1890/subsequent legislation and under SB 888: Generation Pre-AB 1890 - IOUs owned or controlled generation needed to meet demand. Power plants owned by IOUs were regulated by the CPUC on a cost-of-service basis. PURPA introduced competition in the form of QFs, which replaced IOU development of power plants. IOUs bought power from QFs under long-term contracts at the IOUs' avoided cost. Approximately 25% of the electricity demand of IOU customers is now met by QFs. AB 1890/subsequent legislation - The CPUC compelled IOUs to sell fossil power plants to EWGs to facilitate competition and required IOUs to buy and sell all power through the PX at prices set at auction. EWG plants aren't dedicated to serve any particular customers, although EWGs may choose to contract with IOUs (or DWR). Since the enactment of AB 6X in 2001, prices for IOU generation have been set on a cost-of-service basis. For the next few years, the bulk of additional generation needed to meet demand (net short) will be supplied via DWR contracts with EWGs. SB 888 - No fundamental change to regulated/private investment balance, except that CPUC authority to require IOUs to invest in generation is confirmed and cost recovery of reasonable, approved investments is assured. IOU investments must be consistent with an integrated resource plan, which also considers procurement and demand-side alternatives. Transmission Pre-AB 1890 - IOUs owned and operated their transmission. IOUs gave priority access for delivery of power to their customers. Excess capacity was available for wholesale wheeling. AB 1890/subsequent legislation - IOUs still own transmission lines, but operational control is transferred to the ISO. ISO manages the three IOUs' transmission grids as a single, open access system. IOU generation has no more access to the system than competing generators and marketers. SB 888 - No fundamental change, except responsibility for inspection, maintenance, repair and replacement standards for IOU transmission facilities is returned to the CPUC from the ISO. Federal open access mandate remains. Retail Service Pre-AB 1890 - IOUs have an obligation to provide universal service and customers must take bundled service from the IOU at rates set by the CPUC. Self-generation and municipalization are long-term service alternatives. AB 1890/subsequent legislation - IOUs retain the obligation to provide universal service, but IOU customers may buy electricity from retail competitors at unregulated prices, to be delivered by the IOU, and may freely depart and return to bundled IOU service. IOU customers attempt to recover IOU investments made on behalf of direct access customers through a non-bypassable "competition transition charge." In 2001, direct access was suspended to support AB 1X's long-term contracting effort, but not before the direct access load returned to its historic levels and created new stranded costs. IOU customers attempt to recover DWR investments made on behalf of direct access customers through "cost recovery surcharge." SB 888 - Retail service returns to pre-AB 1890 model, where IOUs have an obligation to provide universal service and customers must take bundled service from the IOU at rates set by the CPUC. Existing direct access customers remain on direct access for the duration of their existing contracts. Self-generation and municipalization remain as long-term service alternatives. Community aggregation, where a city or county provides universal direct access service to willing residents, is retained as a service alternative as well. 2.Does this bill repeal deregulation? The Legislature itself did not enact deregulation, and it cannot itself repeal it. Deregulation has been effected by a complex array of mostly federal and some state statutes, regulatory orders and court decisions dating back at least to 1978. PURPA and EPACT deregulated wholesale generation. EPACT and FERC actions such as Orders 888, 889 and 2000 deregulated IOU-owned transmission to accommodate the delivery of non-utility generation. These federal policies are not reversible, although states can choose the extent to which they wish to participate in their implementation. Some states have resisted these federal policies by maintaining vertically integrated utilities. California did not resist, and in AB 1890 consented to and furthered the dis-integration of California's major IOUs, leaving distribution utilities without the means under their control to meet their obligation to serve. Municipal utilities have resisted and remained vertically integrated. The results, in terms of retail rates, speak for themselves. AB 1890 contained a mix of provisions, some furthered deregulation policies and some weren't policies at all, but essentially commercial bargains between interested groups. The Legislature has already taken several individual steps to reverse deregulation. This bill take the further step of repealing the policy of direct access, and attempting to phase out its existing practice. As noted above, direct access is the central deregulation policy initiated by AB 1890 and subject to exclusive state jurisdiction. This bill also affirmatively reverses the retreat from long-term planning, which is another characteristic of electricity deregulation. 3.Who pays for the investments (and the mistakes)? The lesson of deregulation and the energy crisis is that the buck stops with ordinary IOU customers, who are the ultimate source of investment in electricity infrastructure. As such, providers of electricity service should be accountable to them. IOU cost overruns, unjust "market-based" wholesale prices, and the costs of providing back-up service to customer-speculators have not been borne equitably by IOUs, their holding companies, merchant generators or marketers. These costs have been borne by electricity consumers, in particular the 98% of IOU customers who take bundled service and rely on the CPUC and FERC to ensure their rates are reasonable. 4.Are ending power plant divestitures and employee layoffs realistic policy goals? This bill includes as policy goals "stopping electric plant divestiture" and "ending employee layoffs" (Section 4). These are stated as policy goals intended to be pursued by the Legislature. The bill also includes an operative provision extending the current prohibition on power plant divestiture from 2006 to 2010 (Section 33). Both may be desirable general policies, but there are exceptions. For example, the divestiture prohibition limits an IOU's ability to undertake projects which may very well be in the public interest, such as decommissioning of uneconomic hydroelectric facilities to achieve water quality and aquatic habitat goals, without first receiving legislative authorization. The author and committee may wish to consider whether these provisions should be amended to reflect the fact that there may be appropriate exceptions. 5.Basis of regulatory compact. Section 6 of this bill describes the terms of a "regulatory compact" between IOUs and the CPUC. The regulatory compact has previously been an implied agreement which suggests utilities are entitled to a territorial monopoly on service and allowed to earn a limited profit in exchange for the obligation to provide service to all customers in that territory. The duties of the IOUs and the CPUC in this section are drawn from the American Law Institute's Restatement of the Law, Second, Agency, which describes the legal duties of agents to principals, and vice-versa. 6.Holding company provision. When it authorized the formation of IOU holding companies, the CPUC enumerated a number of conditions in its decisions, including the so-called "first priority" condition, which requires IOU holding companies to give first priority to the capital requirements of the IOU necessary to meet its obligation to serve. In response to the CPUC's investigation into the applicability of the "first priority" condition, IOUs have argued that the CPUC has no jurisdiction to enforce such conditions. In Section 45, this bill clarifies that the CPUC indeed retains the authority to monitor and enforce the conditions it imposed on the formation of IOU holding companies. SB 429 (Morrow) contains an IOU holding company provision similar to this bill. The author and the committee may wish to consider whether this bill should be amended to be consistent with SB 429 or whether this provision should be removed from this bill in favor of addressing it in SB 429. SB 429 is pending in the Senate Appropriations Committee. 7.Support and Opposition. This bill is supported by consumer groups, labor groups and municipal utilities. It is opposed by electricity generators and marketers, IOUs, and direct access customers. Supporters and opponents make some similar observations, but reach different conclusions. In general, supporters argue: The state lacks a coherent energy policy direction, which has contributed to the delay in necessary infrastructure investments. Phase out of direct access is vital because direct access discourages long-term planning and investment by IOUs. Supporters state that cost shifting to bundled customers is inevitable under direct access, as demonstrated by recent CPUC decisions, and that direct access is anathema to restoring the obligation to serve. This bill builds on recent progress in the wake of the energy crisis. In general, opponents argue just the opposite: This bill interferes with recent progress, destabilizes the electricity market, creates uncertainty, and discourages investment. Regulation is inefficient and costly, better to assign investment risks (and rewards) to the private sector. Direct access providers and customers argue for the preservation of direct access, and argue the CPUC is dealing effectively with cost shifting. 8.Related Legislation. AB 428 (Richman) and AB 816 (Reyes) repeal the suspension of direct access. AB 428 and AB 816 are pending in the Assembly Appropriations Committee. POSITIONS Sponsor: Authors Support: California Labor Federation, AFL-CIO California Municipal Utilities Association City of Roseville Coalition of California Utility Employees Congress of California Seniors Consumer Federation of California Consumers Union Foundation for Taxpayer and Consumer Rights Northern California Power Agency Southern California Edison (if amended) Southern California Public Power Authority The Utility Reform Network (TURN) Utility Consumers' Action Network 61 individuals Oppose: --------------------------------------------------------------------- |AES Pacific | | |Alliance for Retail Energy Markets | | |APS Energy Services | | |Automated Power Exchange | | |Caithness Energy | | |California Biomass Energy Alliance | | |California Business Properties Association | | |California Business Roundtable | | |California Chamber of Commerce | | |California Independent Petroleum Association | | |California Manufacturers and Technology | | |Association | | |California Retailers Association | | |California Wind Energy Association | | |Callaway Golf Company | | |Calpine Corporation | | |City of Corona | | |Clean Power Campaign | | |Covanta Energy | | |Dynegy | | |Enpower Corporation | | |Heraeus Metal Processing, Inc. | | |Independent Energy Producers | | |Los Angeles Unified School District (unless | | |amended) | | |Minnesota Methane | | |National Energy Marketers Association | | |NRG Energy, Inc. | | |Pacific Gas and Electric Company | | |Public Buildings Service of the U.S. General | | |Services Administration | | |Qualcomm | | |School Project for Utility Rate Reduction | | |Sempra Energy | | |Silicon Valley Manufacturing Group | | |Strategic Energy | | |Sweetwater Union High School District | | |Ultra-Tool International, Inc. | | |USAA Realty Company | | |Verizon | | |Western Power Trading Forum | | |Western States Petroleum Association | | |Whitewater Energy Corporation | | |Wintec Energy | | --------------------------------------------------------------------- Lawrence Lingbloom SB 888 Analysis Hearing Date: May 6, 2003